EU Emissions Trading in a Crowded National Climate Policy Space - Some findings from the INTERACT project

Ergebnisse von TA-Projekten - Neue TA-Projekte

EU Emissions Trading in a Crowded National Climate Policy Space - Some findings from the INTERACT project

by Jos Sijm, Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands (ECN); and Steve Sorrell, Science and Technology Policy Research (SPRU), University of Sussex

Climate policy in EU Member States is becoming increasingly crowded. Multiple instruments have been introduced at both the Member State and EU levels and new instruments are regularly being proposed. As the number of instruments grows, so does the potential for interaction between them. This interaction can be complementary and mutually reinforcing, but there is also the risk that different policy instruments will interfere with one another and undermine the objectives and credibility of each. The central aim of the EU-funded research project “Interaction in EU Climate Policy“ (INTERACT) has been to develop a systematic approach to analysing policy interaction and to use this approach to explore the potential interactions between the proposed EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) and other instruments within both EU and Member State climate policy. [1]

1     The INTERACT project

The INTERACT project was conducted over a two-year period between March 2001 and March 2003. The project was co-ordinated by SPRU (Science and Technology Policy Research) at the University of Sussex (UK), in collaboration with: the Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands (ECN), the Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research (ISI), the Centre International de Recherche sur l'Environnement et le Développement (CIRED), and the Energy Policy Group (EPG) at the National and Kapodistrian University of Athens (NKUA). SPRU was responsible for the overall direction of the project, while each Partner was primarily responsible for empirical research within their own Member State. The Partner institutes in each participating Member State selected a minimum of three national climate policy instruments, examined their potential interactions with the EU ETS and developed a number of policy recommendations. Table 1 summarises the general categories under which the selected instruments fell. Note that there is frequently more than one instrument within each general category. [2]

Table 1: Types of policy instruments examined in each case study

Category UK Netherlands Germany France Greece
Carbon / energy taxes X X X    
Negotiated agreements X X X X  
Support mechanisms for renewable electricity X X X X X
Industrial pollution control X     X X
GHG emissions trading X     X  
Promotion of energy efficiency X        

2     Implications of the EU ETS for Policy Interaction

A defining feature of a “cap and trade“ emissions trading scheme - such as the EU ETS - is that, assuming adequate enforcement and full compliance, there is certainty that total emissions will be equal to the aggregate cap. [3] A second feature of a cap and trade scheme is that, under a standard set of assumptions regarding the competitive operation of the allowance market, the trading scheme will allow the target to be met at least cost. In the equilibrium, marginal abatement costs will be equalised across sources and equal to the allowance price.

These idealised features of an ETS have important implications for policy interaction. Coupled with comparable assumptions regarding the idealised operation of the relevant product markets, they imply that the use of a second instrument that directly or indirectly interacts with the ETS will increase the overall costs of meeting the emissions cap while at the same time having no influence on environmental effectiveness - where the latter is defined as assurance in meeting the ETS cap. The aggregate abatement costs of ETS participants may be either increased (e.g. by a carbon tax) or reduced (e.g. by a subsidy scheme) by the second instrument, but in all cases the aggregate social costs of meeting the cap will be increased and participant emissions will continue to be less than or equal to the cap. This result applies both to instruments which directly affect CO2 emissions from ETS participants, such as a carbon tax on fuel use, and to instruments which indirectly affect those emissions, such as a tax on electricity consumption of both participants and non-participants.

In practice, allowance and product markets may only approximate the theoretical ideal. Market failures will be pervasive in both markets and the political bargaining that led to the ETS cap is unlikely to provide an adequate reflection of the “social optimum“ for carbon externalities (to the extent that such a concept is meaningful for global climate change). In addition, governments have objectives which go beyond efficiency, such as the promotion of social equity. In these circumstances, there may be legitimate grounds for introducing or maintaining other climate policy instruments that directly or indirectly interact with the ETS. These include:

However, the fact that positive combinations between an ETS and other instruments are theoretically possible does not mean that such combinations will result when an ETS is introduced into an existing policy mix. Furthermore, when an ETS is in place, aggregate emission reductions will be set solely by the ETS cap. Instruments which target emissions covered by the ETS cap will contribute nothing further to emission reductions - unless they are sufficiently stringent that they make the ETS redundant. This means that, once the ETS is in place, the justification for maintaining such instruments must rely upon one of the above rationales, rather than the contribution of the instrument to overall emission reductions.

In the following, an example of the possible interaction between the EU ETS and voluntary or “negotiated agreements“ (cf. Table 1) in the Netherlands is outlined.

3     Case study: the interaction between the EU ETS and the Benchmarking Covenant in the Netherlands

The Benchmarking Covenant (BC) is a voluntary agreement, signed in July 1999 by the Dutch government and energy-intensive industry, including the electricity production sector. The central goal of the Benchmarking Covenant is to reduce GHG emissions from energy-intensive industries by improving their energy efficiency without compromising the international competitiveness of these industries. According to the BC, participating industries are required to become close to the world best practice in terms of energy efficiency as soon as possible, but no later than 2012. The interaction between the EU ETS and the BC raises a variety of issues, including:

4     Policy recommendations

The INTERACT project has made a number of specific policy recommendations for each of the participating Member States. These recommendations vary according to the specific circumstances of the Member State and the interpretations given by each of the research teams. But the following general principles of climate policy development may be highlighted:

There is scope for debate over these principles and over the specific recommendations given in each of the case study reports. But the main point is to encourage wider recognition of the challenges and opportunities that the EU ETS creates.

Notes

[1] The proposed EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) is expected to cover some 45 % of EU CO2 emissions from 2005 onwards. Participants include electricity generators, oil refineries and energy intensive manufacturing installations in sectors such as iron and steel, minerals and paper. Phase 1 of the EU ETS runs from 2005 to 2008, and Phase 2 from 2008 to 2012. As the EU ETS expands over time to cover more sectors and greenhouse gases (GHGs), the scheme will cover an increasingly large proportion of the total EU emissions regulated under the UNFCCC/Kyoto Protocol.

[2] Further information on the INTERACT project, including a list of downloadable reports and policy briefs, is available on the web site: http://www.sussex.ac.uk/spru/environment/research/interact.html.

[3] In a cap and trade emissions trading scheme for CO2 emissions, a fixed number of emission allowances are allocated each year to the participating sources. Each participant must surrender one allowance for every tonne of CO2 emitted. Participants who face high abatement costs can continue to emit by buying additional allowances, while participants who face low abatement costs can take abatement action and sell their surplus allowances for a profit. In this way, each participant can minimise its overall abatement costs. The scheme places an overall “cap“ on the annual quantity of CO2 emissions equal to the number of allowances distributed, and the trading mechanism should allow this cap to be achieved at the lowest possible cost.

Kontakt

Jos Sijm
Energy Research Centre of the Netherlands (ECN)
Badhuisweg 3, NL 1031 CM Amsterdam, The Netherlands
Tel: +31 224 568255
E-Mail: sijm∂ecn.nl
Internet: http://www.ecn.nl/